Front. For. Glob. Change Frontiers in Forests and Global Change Front. For. Glob. Change 2624-893X Frontiers Media S.A. 10.3389/ffgc.2023.1062551 Forests and Global Change Original Research Performance insurance for jurisdictional REDD+: Unlocking finance and increasing ambition in large-scale carbon crediting systems Chan Kitty Kay 1 * Golub Alexander 2 Lubowski Ruben 3 1Applied Analytics, Columbia University, New York, NY, United States 2Department of Environmental Science, American University, Washington, DC, United States 3Climate and Environmental Solutions, Lombard Odier Investment Managers, New York, NY, United States

Edited by: Hisham Zerriffi, University of British Columbia, Canada

Reviewed by: Emi Uchida, University of Rhode Island, United States; Albert Arhin, Kwame Nkrumah University of Science and Technology, Ghana

*Correspondence: Kitty Kay Chan kkc2139@columbia.edu

This article was submitted to Forest Management, a section of the journal Frontiers in Forests and Global Change

†These authors have contributed equally to this work and share first authorship

09 03 2023 2023 6 1062551 06 10 2022 25 01 2023 Copyright © 2023 Chan, Golub and Lubowski. 2023 Chan, Golub and Lubowski

This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

Introduction

Jurisdictional pay-for-performance systems, with nested accounting of smaller project activities, offer potential to more rapidly scale up carbon finance for reducing deforestation as well as to ensure greater environmental integrity compared to stand-alone projects. However, the design and implementation of such programs raise numerous challenges, including for mobilizing upfront investment when there is a risk of non-performance at the jurisdictional level. This paper provides the first analysis to examine the use of insurance mechanisms to mitigate this jurisdictional delivery risk.

Methods

A conceptual model based on the theory of individual choice under uncertainty is developed to examine the impact of performance uncertainty on large-scale reductions in emissions from deforestation and forest degradation (REDD+). We calibrate the model to perform simulations of how reductions could change with and without the availability of revenue insurance as well as of a carbon buffer to manage performance risks.

Results

Performance uncertainty constrains the potential for large-scale mitigation supply when payments are contingent on emissions falling below a threshold level and when it is important to break even on payments to domestic actors. We show that insurance would allow jurisdictions to increase emissions reductions despite this uncertainty and that building a performance buffer offers nonlinear potential to unlock supply in a complementary manner.

Discussion

Private insurers, together with philanthropic and public funders, have a critical role to play in establishing an insurance market that can de-risk jurisdictional program investments and unlock forest conservation and other climate and nature protection efforts at scale.

carbon market credits emissions deforestation insurance jurisdictional performance risk REDD+

香京julia种子在线播放

    1. <form id=HxFbUHhlv><nobr id=HxFbUHhlv></nobr></form>
      <address id=HxFbUHhlv><nobr id=HxFbUHhlv><nobr id=HxFbUHhlv></nobr></nobr></address>

      1. Introduction

      At the Leaders' Climate Summit in April 2021, the United States, the United Kingdom, and Norway, and nine other companies announced the LEAF Coalition, a public–private partnership to protect tropical forests using forward commitments and price guarantees to pay at least $1 billion for emissions reductions at large jurisdictional (national and state/province) scales (Lubowski, 2021). Jurisdictional crediting systems, with nested accounting of smaller scale project-scale activities, offer the potential to more rapidly scale up emissions reductions as well as to ensure greater environmental integrity compared to stand-alone small projects (Schwartzman et al., 2021; DeFries et al., 2022). However, the design and implementation of such large-scale nested crediting systems raise numerous practical challenges that are only beginning to be considered.

      This study focuses on addressing the risk to potential funders, jurisdictions, and nested project implementers (e.g., indigenous communities, private project developers, and landowners) when carbon credits or other result-based payments depend on the uncertain performance of an entire jurisdiction below a crediting baseline. In particular, this study develops a theoretical and simulation model to provide the first quantitative analysis to examine the use of insurance to mitigate this jurisdictional performance risk. The study examines the very particular risk posed within a jurisdictional and nested crediting structure of whether actors implementing activities that are nested within the jurisdiction can, in fact, receive the full market price for reductions or whether this price might be discounted due to jurisdiction-wide underperformance relative to the larger scale crediting baseline.

      A conceptual model is developed to examine potential approaches to mitigate this risk based on the theory of individual choice under uncertainty (Mas-Colell et al., 1995; Hayashi, 2021). The model captures the situation in which the jurisdictional authorities are uncertain about the aggregate production that the jurisdiction can achieve due to various factors including the volatility of future agricultural commodity prices, which could increase the opportunity cost of protecting forests. These unexpected developments may lead policymakers and/or the implementing agents to fail to deliver the expected levels of emission reductions.

      We calibrate the model to perform simulations to examine how the level of emission reductions might change with and without the use of revenue insurance as well as the willingness to pay to avoid risks of nonperformance. We also examine the option for jurisdictions to access a carbon buffer to hedge against performance risks. The results show that such approaches to insurance have the potential to play an important role in reducing the barriers to public and private investment to scale up emission reductions under jurisdictional scale programs.

      2. Large-scale crediting

      There is growing scientific and stakeholder consensus that carbon finance for reducing deforestation should quickly be moving toward accounting at large, jurisdictional scales (e.g., countries or states), with crediting of smaller project-based activities “nested” or integrated within the larger accounting framework (e.g., COICA, 2023). Jurisdictional crediting aligns with the decisions on REDD+ under the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change as affirmed under the Paris Agreement, as well as the standards for REDD+ approved by compliance carbon markets, notably for international civil aviation as well as California.

      Crediting systems based on the performance of an entire jurisdiction offer the potential to incentivize governments to pursue policy reforms and other measures that only governments can do. Large-scale accounting over both space and time brings important advantages in terms of environmental integrity, including capturing any leakage or shifts in deforestation within a jurisdiction (Schwartzman et al., 2021). Jurisdictional crediting also creates incentives for law enforcement, recognition of indigenous rights, and other policy measures that only the government can implement. Large-scale accounting also provides greater potential assurance of “additionality” (ensuring that the activity would not have happened anyway) by, for example, avoiding self-selection, which is inherent when smaller projects are free to voluntarily opt-in to participate in the program (van Benthem and Kerr, 2013). Large-scale accounting also supports systemic changes that can better assure “permanence” (ensuring that the climate benefits will not later be reversed) (Schwartzman et al., 2021; DeFries et al., 2022).

      The LEAF Coalition represents an important step in terms of demonstrating both private sector and public sector willingness to pay for credits provided via jurisdictional systems as well as interest from various jurisdictions to develop credits. Nevertheless, there are various practical challenges to scaling up the implementation of jurisdictional and nested systems, including how to operate a multi-layer payment for environmental services program (Wunder et al., 2020).

      An important feature of REDD+ is that it is result-based such that payments are made for results delivered, ensuring efficient use of climate resources and providing local actors with flexibility for implementation. However, when the achievement of a certain level of forest protection and resulting emissions reductions is uncertain, this creates a delivery risk for a jurisdiction and/or funders or investors supporting the jurisdiction that must make investments up front to later receive payments for certified emission reductions.

      2.1. A numerical example of uncertain jurisdictional supply

      In this section, we explain how to build a probabilistic REDD+ supply function and develop an illustrative numerical example based on estimated uncertainty in the opportunity costs of forest protection. The government or other developers of a large-scale deforestation reduction program will face uncertainty about the resulting outcome from the interventions at a large scale. For example, natural disturbances, increases in commodity prices, or changes in government policy (e.g., at the federal level) might make it harder than expected for a jurisdiction to reduce emissions. We develop a stylized example where there is uncertainty over the marginal costs of reducing deforestation in a jurisdiction. For a stylized example, we focus on uncertainty in the opportunity costs of reducing deforestation. This will play an important role in determining the response of deforestation to jurisdictional programs, including incentive programs for conversation where land managers will trade off these benefits against the benefits of alternative land use. Opportunity costs will also determine the extent to which actors will take the risk of pursuing illegal deforestation, which could result in fines or other penalties.

      We use data from global analyses to develop a stylized numerical example. We take the shape of a marginal cost function from the study by Busch et al. (2019), which uses an econometric approach to estimate the opportunity costs of tropical deforestation globally. Estimated costs are in present discounted values, considering 30 years of agricultural revenues and a real discount rate of 10%. This econometric approach captures the actual response of deforestation to changes in economic incentives for converting land and provides a more conservative estimate of the potential for reducing emissions than other modeling studies. Based on the shape of the curves estimated by Busch et al. (2019), we fit a quadratic function for mean values of emissions reductions supply for the different price levels and then scale down the global curve by 0.75% to construct a representative jurisdictional marginal abatement cost curve (MACC). This scaling was used for illustrative purposes, as it is the share of global deforestation emissions represented by a major forest jurisdiction in the Amazon. This yields an average estimated supply of 150 million metric tons (150 Mt) at $100/tCO2, which is approximately the average level of annual emissions over the past decade in the state of Mato Grosso, Brazil, the largest agricultural state in the Brazilian Amazon.1

      To account for uncertainty, we apply the 95% confidence interval (95% CI) of supply from tropical forest conservation at $100/tCO2 reported by Griscom et al. (2017). We express the 95% CI in multiples of the mean: 0.48–1.52μ (or 0.61–1.42μ in 90CI), where μ denotes the mean value of supply. Using this range, the resulting 90th confidence interval is 92–213 Mt at $100/tCO2. A narrower confidence interval could reflect incentives created by the jurisdictional implementation program that reduces uncertainty in actors' responses to payments or other interventions. Different types of interventions and program designs could be associated with different levels of uncertainty. We consider a single cost curve for illustration purposes. Furthermore, for illustration purposes, we allow slight asymmetry in the distribution, fitting a lognormal distribution with a mean value of 150 million tCO2 and 185 million tCO2 in the 95th percentile of the distribution. A more precise assessment of the supply distribution requires a specific analysis of different risk factors, which is beyond the scope of our study.

      The next step is the estimation of the probability distribution for coefficients of a quadratic function to match the supply distribution at $100/tCO2. The illustrative MACC has a form p = aQ2 + bQ where p stands for marginal cost and Q denotes emissions reduction. For calibration, we use log-normal distributions for each coefficient with a mean value equal to the value of the coefficient estimated for the mean value of emissions reduction. To calibrate the standard deviation of the confidence interval, we used an unsupervised randomized algorithm and selected the pair of values corresponding to the best fit of 90CI. The median value of the marginal abatement supply curve and the uncertainty range in the 90th confidence interval are presented in Figure 1.

      Uncertainty range of jurisdictional abatement supply (90th confidence interval).

      The figure shows the degree of uncertainty of marginal costs to secure a given supply of emissions reductions. However, further analysis is needed to know the distribution of supply at a given price. Solving the quadratic equation aQ2 + bQp = 0, we express Q as a function of p. The exact supply is uncertain, so we need to estimate this degree of uncertainty based on the information we know already. Since we already know the probability density functions for coefficients a and b, we can compute the distribution of the supply of emissions reductions for each carbon price level. The distribution of emissions reductions and the shift to higher values as prices rise are shown for three illustrative price levels ($20, $25, and $30/tCO2) in Figure 2, based on 10,000 trials of a Monte Carlo simulation for each price.

      Distribution of jurisdictional emissions reductions under different carbon prices. Note: The violin plots show a kernel density estimation of the distribution of emission reduction outcomes based on 10,000 trials of a Monte Carlo simulation for each indicated price. The lower and upper edges of the rectangles in the box plots denote the interquartile range (25th and 75th percentiles), with the horizontal lines and crosses denoting the median and mean values, respectively.

      A jurisdiction will likely need to meet a minimum required reduction threshold Q¯, before it is eligible to generate creditable emissions reductions. For example, under the ART-TREES standard, buffer requirements (to insure against the risk of credited emissions reductions being reversed in subsequent periods) range from 0 to 45% of reductions below the baseline, depending on mitigating factors. There is an added leakage deduction (to address the additional risk of deforestation shifting to areas outside of the jurisdiction) of up to 5% for subnational jurisdictions (ART, 2021). As an illustration, we consider Q¯=35 million, which is 23% of 150, the mean abatement available and 19% of the 95% of 185 million tCO2. The market supply curve then shifts left, as shown in Supplementary Figure S1, such that at least 35 million tCO2 must be reduced before any credits can be generated.

      Supplementary Figure S1 presents uncertainty in costs and potentially creditable emissions supply that can be offered to potential buyers with Q¯=35 million. If the jurisdiction aims to reduce emissions by 20 million tCO2, the 90CI cost is $4.6 to $9.4, as shown in Figure 1, but to generate 20 million tCO2 of credits, the cost is $15.6 to $33.6, as shown in Supplementary Figure S1, since the emissions reductions achieved must now be 55 million tCO2.

      If the jurisdiction offers implementing agents $20/tCO2, the supply of emission reductions in the 90CI is 37.6 to 65 million tCO2, but the jurisdiction can receive credit for only 2.6 to 30 million tCO2, as shown in Figure 1 and Supplementary Figure S1, respectively. If the jurisdiction signed contracts to sell 22.6 million tCO2 at $20/tCO2, the probability of failing to deliver that quantity is 5% (22.6 million tCO2 is the value of creditable supply in the 95th percentile at a $20 price). With a probability of 0.95 or higher, however, the actual supply of creditable emissions reductions will be ≥22.6 million tCO2.

      This uncertainty creates a challenge for jurisdiction and its counterparties, both external and internal. What can a jurisdiction—or investors in a jurisdictional program—commit to paying internally, given that the realization of emissions reductions will be uncertain?

      3. Conceptual model

      In this section, we propose a conceptual model to describe the jurisdiction's challenge in terms of managing ex-ante investments given the uncertain supply. We then examine potential approaches to mitigate the performance risk based on the theory of individual choice under uncertainty (Mas-Colell et al., 1995; Hayashi, 2021). The model incorporates the option for jurisdictions to access a carbon performance buffer by purchasing insurance, with an adjusted price based on historical performance to hedge against these performance risks.

      We then calibrate the model to perform simulations to examine how the level of emission reductions might change with and without the use of the insurance mechanism and the impact on social welfare that jurisdiction would in theory be willing to pay to avoid such risk and the actual payment under an actuarial fair full coverage policy.

      3.1. The jurisdiction's investment challenge

      Let Q equal the verified reductions in emissions (abatement) that a jurisdiction achieves during a crediting period, annual, or otherwise, such that Q = EBE where E denotes the verified emissions during the crediting period and EB is a counterfactual “baseline” for emissions, based on either historical levels or future projections that provides a benchmark against which emissions reductions might be calculated. For example, the ART-TREES standard used by the LEAF Coalition uses a 5-year historical average of emissions as the crediting line for a 5-year crediting period, with a requirement for this to readjust downward in each subsequent period (ART, 2021). For simplicity, we only consider the example of a single crediting period in our current model.

      In practice, some standards provide additional requirements for the jurisdiction to further reduce emissions below the baseline before payments can be made. These requirements might be a minimum level of “own effort” that the jurisdiction might need to achieve (e.g., 15% below a 10-year historical average under the California Tropical Forest Standard) as well as additional deductions to ensure conservative crediting or to establish a buffer account to help insure against future reversals. Let Q¯=EB- E¯ where E¯ equals the crediting baseline, the level of emissions that the jurisdiction must fall under before it can start to sell reductions to the international market. We denote Q¯ as the minimum abatement requirement for crediting and assuming it is exogenous and is pre-agreed upon between the jurisdiction and its potential buyers in an international market.

      Given Q¯, we now consider the jurisdiction's challenge of how much to invest in reducing emissions given the uncertainty over the resulting supply, as discussed earlier. We make some simplifying assumptions. First, to focus on the issue of uncertain supply, we consider the potential international price as fixed and do not consider possible uncertainty in prices and possible strategies for handling that. Therefore, we consider that the jurisdiction can contract in advance for guaranteed payment from the international market at the price Pg emission reduction per ton for quantity achieved above the minimum abatement requirement for crediting.

      Second, given this Pg, we consider that the jurisdiction offers a single fixed price per ton to its domestic implementing agents and that this must be committed to ex-ante. We assume that the jurisdiction pays the domestic agents fully for their emissions reductions once they are verified, but this does not depend on the aggregate performance of the jurisdiction. Thus, the individual agents bear the risk of their respective projects delivering reductions, but it is the jurisdiction, rather than the implementing agents, that bears the aggregate performance risk relative to the minimum requirement for crediting. Given its broader set of policy tools, the jurisdiction may be better able to manage risks at the landscape level than at the individual agent level. For simplicity, since our focus is on the aggregate performance risk, we assume the jurisdiction pays fully for any realized emissions reductions delivered by the local agents, without conditioning payments on a minimum quantity delivered at the individual project level. The best way to manage project-level delivery risks is a potential topic for other research.

      In practice, jurisdictions can be expected to implement a mix of programmatic activities with different marginal costs, and that it may wish to offer different payments to local actors according to these activities. However, for simplicity, we consider the case where the jurisdiction simply offers a single fixed price per ton to domestic actors. The jurisdiction, thus, simply commits to paying local agents Pd, with 0 < Pdg, for each ton of emission reduction achieved. The jurisdiction's domestic price equals Pd = (1 − δ)Pg where 0 ≤ δ ≤ 1 is a “withholding rate” or share of the global price per ton that the jurisdiction does not directly pass on to local actors. We assume that δ is positive as a negative δ would imply the jurisdiction extracts a net tax rather than making a net payment to domestic actors. This could also be considered the case where the jurisdiction allows nested project-scale activities, integrated within the jurisdictional accounting to directly access the international market, with the requirement to contribute a percentage δ to the jurisdictional authority toward covering the costs (including managing the aggregate performance risks) of the larger program.

      Third, we assume that the jurisdiction is budget-constrained and must fully cover the costs of the jurisdictional program with the revenues that it can earn from the sale of credits. To focus on the carbon market design challenges, we assume the jurisdiction is not able to use other public or philanthropic revenues toward underwriting the costs to produce other social and environmental benefits of the program, including any profits earned by domestic actors. Thus, the jurisdiction's constraint is to “break-even” on the program in terms of the revenues it receives from the carbon market. This can also be envisioned as a situation where the jurisdictional program is funded by private investors, including through potential bond issuance, and these investors must be paid back based on carbon revenues, with no other revenue streams available.

      For the jurisdiction, the total payment collected from the international market must thus be equal to or greater than the total payment necessary to compensate the domestic agents. Thus, the total number of tons of emission reductions achieved by domestic agents needs to meet the following break-even condition, given fixed levels of Pg and Q¯, and the jurisdiction's chosen Pd:

      Pg(Q^- Q¯)= PdQ^

      Substituting for Pd yields:

      Pg(Q^- Q¯)= (1-δ)PgQ^

      This can be simplified as follows:

      (Q^- Q¯)= (1-δ)Q^

      This implies as follows:

      Q^= Q¯δ

      Q^ is the minimum number of total tons of emission reduction the jurisdiction needs to achieve to break even. The break-even quantity is inversely proportional to the withholding level of the global price δ and must be equal to (when δ = 1) or greater than (for δ < 1) the threshold level Q¯. The smaller the withholding, all else equal, the less revenues the government collects and the greater the level of emissions reductions required for the jurisdiction to break even on its payments to the implementing agents and vice versa.

      Rewriting the formula in terms of the withholding rate as follows:

      δ= Q¯Q^

      This yields a feasible schedule of Pd= (1-δ)Pg=(1-Q¯Q^)Pg to ensure break even. As a numerical example, we return to the example of jurisdiction with Q¯= 35. Figure 3 shows the feasible combination (loci) of domestic abatement prices and quantities that ensure break even, depending on different levels of global prices for credits from $20 to $90/tCO2. The jurisdiction cannot offer anything to local actors until the quantity of emissions reductions exceeds the threshold Q¯ and in turn can offer more, as the realized quantity increases such that more credits are generated that can be sold internationally. All else equal, more can also be offered to local actors, as the global price increases. Thus, the actual quantity of emission reductions realized at the jurisdictional level, Q could generally fall under one of the following scenarios: (i) below the minimum emission reduction requirement Q¯ and not eligible to receive payment from the international market, (ii) above the minimum requirement for crediting but not covering the payment required to reimburse the total number of tons of emission reduced by domestic agents Q, and (iii) above Q¯ and covering the total payment required to reimburse the domestic agents so as to break even.

      Feasible combinations of domestic abatement prices and quantities consistent with break even, by different global prices for credits. Note: For each level of domestic prices paid for abatement, lines denote the minimum quantities of realized abatement that ensure break-even, given the indicated global price for credits. The minimum abatement requirement (Q¯) is assumed to be 35 million tCO2 such that international payments are only made for abatement exceeding that level.

      The jurisdiction aims to achieve an emission reduction level at or above the break-even level Q^ but faces the challenge of being uncertain about the aggregate emission reduction that it will achieve at any given price. Even with no information asymmetry among jurisdictions and implementing agents, the jurisdictional authorities and the implementing agents still face other factors including the volatility of future agricultural commodity prices, which could increase the opportunity cost of protecting forests. These unexpected developments may lead policymakers and/or the implementing agents to decide not to deliver the expected levels of emission reductions. This challenge is illustrated in Figure 4, which combines the information in Figures 1, 3. This shows that a price of $20 is no longer sufficient for the jurisdiction to break even within the 90% confidence interval of supply. With an international price of $50, the jurisdiction can offer around $20 so as to break even with the 95th top percentile of supply (i.e., with just a 5% probability of achieving that level) while a price of around $70 is needed to offer around $25 and approach the median (50th percentile) level of supply. A price of around $90 is needed for the jurisdiction to offer approximately $35 and generate supply at the 5% percentile level (i.e., with a 95% probability of achieving that level).

      Abatement supply curve and feasible combinations (in blue) of domestic abatement prices and quantities consistent with the jurisdiction breaking even. Note: Figure combines information shown in Figures 1, 3. For each level of domestic prices paid for abatement, lines in blue denote the minimum quantities of realized abatement that ensure break-even, given the indicated global price for credits. Assumed minimum abatement requirement (Q¯) equals 35 million tCO2 such that international payments are only made for abatement exceeding that level.

      Higher domestic prices will stimulate greater supply, given the upward sloping supply curve, but also in turn require higher emissions reductions to break even as a result of the higher costs that must be recovered. Figure 4 shows that under certain circumstances, there may be multiple domestic prices that generate supply with the same level of confidence in breaking even. For example, at the $50 global price and 95% of supply (i.e., with a 5% probability of achieving it), break even can be achieved with a domestic price from around $15/ton to $25/ton, reducing 45–70 million tCO2, respectively. Higher global prices are needed to break even with a greater level of probability.

      Therefore, even with relatively high international prices, in the presence of a performance threshold, a jurisdiction (or investors in its program) may lack sufficient certainty of cost recovery to commit to paying its domestic actors. In the next section, we consider the potential role of insurance to help manage the jurisdiction's performance risk and unlock greater jurisdictional supply.

      3.2. The role of insurance in managing the risk of jurisdictional performance

      To mitigate the risk of not meeting the break-even quantity, we consider the case where a jurisdiction is provided with the opportunity to purchase a specialized form of insurance. For simplicity, we consider a form of revenue insurance that will top up the jurisdiction's net revenues to ensure these will always be at or above a desired level and at or better than break even. We assume the supplier of the insurance prices the insurance at an actuarially fair rate, such that the price charged exactly equals the expected payout, adjusted for the anticipated probabilities of the different outcomes given all available information. As jurisdictions establish a track level of jurisdictional performance, the organization can continue to adjust the price of its insurance upwards or downwards incorporating the information that is revealed to the actual performance risks. As discussed in the conclusion, insurance might also be provided through a physical carbon buffer that the jurisdiction could establish and then use as a reserve of tons that can later be tapped upon if needed to cover a shortfall in emission reductions.

      This section outlines a conceptual model for the provision of actuarially fair insurance to insure the authority governing the program against risks of different levels of jurisdictional non-performance, with the full mathematical details provided in the Supplementary material. We consider the risks of achieving the emissions reductions needed for the authority to receive payments from the international market as well as to fully cover the costs of implementing its program. We consider different potential states of the world defined in terms of the realization of emissions reductions Qk indexed by k = 0…Qmax. We use Qh to denote the total number of tons of emission reductions achieved when the quantity realized is at a “high” level. Qh ranges at or above the break-even quantity Q^ up to a maximum abatement potential Qmax. Furthermore, wh represents the associated “wealth” level of the jurisdiction given Qh. Assuming administrative costs are zero for simplicity, the wealth level of the jurisdiction is defined as the net revenues from the REDD+ program that are retained by the jurisdictional program authority:

      wh=Pg (Qh-Q¯ )-Pd Qh, given Qh  Q^

      Assuming the probability pk of any realization Qk given Pd, then for a given domestic price Pd, and threshold Q¯, the expected level of wealth equals the sum of the net revenues weighted by the associated probabilities for all possible realizations of quantity where Qh Q^ as follows:

      E[wh]=k=Q^Qmaxpk( Pg(Qhk-Q¯ )-Pd Qhk), given Qhk  Q^

      As noted earlier, we focus on the problem of a governmental authority concerned about ensuring a budget surplus. Nevertheless, the issues are also applicable to the case of public or private investors funding the jurisdiction, or potentially, other actors such as an indigenous community directly implementing a large-scale emission reduction program. We further assume a degree of risk aversion. For simplicity, the jurisdiction only considers its own budget situation and does consider the overall economic surplus that agents within the jurisdiction may be earning from the program. This is likely to be the case at least for a fraction of REDD+ program revenues, as well as the case for commercial investors simply seeking financial returns whether through a bond or other structures.

      We use Ql to denote the total number of tons of emission reductions achieved when the realized quantity is “low” such that the break-even quantity has not been reached. The jurisdiction will only receive payment from the international market if Ql is above Q¯. However, it always must bear the committed costs of the quantity of emission reductions realized at the domestic level by local agents.

      We illustrate two different “low” scenarios and the corresponding levels of wealth: wl1 is the wealth in “low” case 1 where no revenues are received at all since the quantity falls below Q¯, and wl2 is the wealth in “low” case 2 where Q¯ is exceeded but the realized quantity falls below the necessary level Q^ to achieve break even. We distinguish these two cases given that the type of risk may be perceived differently by the jurisdiction and the insurance providers. The jurisdiction may want to insure against both wl1 and wl2. However, some insurers may only want to insure against wl2, as they may want the jurisdiction to at least have some minimal performance requirement, given potential concerns about moral hazard as discussed later.

      We assume the jurisdiction is risk-averse with a concave utility function, u(·). While the precise results will vary with the specific functional form applied, the use of an exponential utility function is most suitable for our illustrative examples, as it allows for capturing risk aversion and the utility level corresponding to a negative wealth level. This characteristic is particularly important for the problem analyzed here where the jurisdiction runs the risk of negative net revenues, as it must pay its domestic agents for realized emissions reductions even if the jurisdiction as a whole does not meet the minimum abatement requirement for crediting. In addition, even if the jurisdiction meets Q¯ but does not achieve Q^, its wealth level, measured as net government revenues, could still be negative.

      To simplify, we restrict attention here to the case where the jurisdiction seeks to fully ensure against the case of not meeting Qh, which is at or above Q^. We examine the implications of insurance for emission reductions and gains in economic surplus in the insurance market. We restrict considerations of economic surplus to the consumer surplus associated with the willingness to pay off the jurisdictional authorities (and/or potential funders) from purchasing the insurance contract.

      In our scenario, the insuring organization in this case is not profit-making such that it does not earn a producer surplus. To simplify the model, we also assume no administrative costs associated with the insurance provision. The actuarially fair price for a full insurance policy equals the expected cost, C, equal to the probability of not meeting the insured-against quantity Qh multiplied by the benefit payout, B, to jurisdictions when the quantity is not achieved.

      Expanding on Frank (2021), the consumer surplus, CS, captures the difference between the premium the jurisdiction pays for the insurance, C, and the maximum willingness to pay MWTP, for insurance, against failing to meet its goal Qh, as follows:

      CS = MWTP- E[C]

      MWTP is the difference between the total wealth generated by the jurisdiction when it achieves its goal, wh, and the certainty equivalent CE, which is the minimum monetary amount that the jurisdiction is willing to accept in order not to take the risk of not meeting a particular higher but uncertain quantity. The MWTPl to avoid both “low” states 1 and 2 is as follows:

      MWTPl= wh-CE

      Certainty equivalence can be derived by setting the expected utility of wealth generated by the jurisdiction to the utility of the certainty equivalent (Mas-Colell et al., 1995).

      E[u(w)]= u(CE)

      In practice, it will be difficult to price this insurance in an exactly actuarially precise manner. However, over time, a jurisdiction that has proven to have a better record in meeting its threshold for crediting and break-even level should be eligible to access the insurance at a discounted price. This can be considered a simplified representation of a form of Bayesian updating of the prior probabilities associated with each of the “low” states. Thus, the jurisdiction is assigned a set of performance risk scores, γ with 0 ≤ γ ≤ 1, such that

      E[C]=γE[C]

      γ = 1 indicates the jurisdiction receives no discount, while the better a jurisdiction's performance in meeting the crediting threshold and break-even quantity, the lower its risk score applied to its future performance.

      4. Simulations

      We now calibrate the conceptual model to examine (i) the emission reduction level with and without the use of the insurance mechanism and (ii) the impact on economic welfare in terms of a jurisdiction's willingness to pay to avoid the risk of not meeting its emission reduction goal. As per the stylized numerical example mentioned earlier, the minimum threshold requirement Q¯ is 35 million tCO2. We later consider alternative scenarios with lower levels of this threshold.

      International prices for REDD+ credits in the voluntary market were approximately $4 in 2021 (Ecosystem Marketplace, 2022) but have risen sharply. Voluntary market prices for credits are forecast to reach $80—$150 by 2030 (EY, 2022). We examine the global price range between $30 and $90 with $20 increments. The prices offered to domestic agents are set to vary in $1 increments up to the global price.

      We consider the case where the jurisdiction chooses a target level of wealth associated with the emission reduction goal, Qh*, which is set at the 50th percentile of expected probability such that πh=0.5. For each level of domestic price Pd, each potential Qk and its associated probability pk are derived using the probability density function as shown in Figure 2.

      Studies have suggested that risk tolerance R typically ranges from 100 to 150% of net income (McNamee and Celona, 1990; Kirkwood, 2004). While the tolerance might be higher for a jurisdiction than for individuals, for purposes of illustration, we use 125%, the mid-point of this range. Under the global prices ranging between $30 and $90 with $5 increments at 125%, R is approximately $60, $108, $250, and $204 million when the minimum threshold requirement Q¯ as 35, 25, 15, and 5 million tCO2, respectively. In practice, the risk tolerance level can be adjusted by a jurisdictional program authority to calibrate such analysis to the level of risk that it can bear.

      As shown in Figure 4, with a minimum abatement requirement for crediting at 35 million tCO2, global prices of $30/tCO2 and $50/tCO2 are not high enough to induce emission reduction levels (at the 50th percentile) that would be at or higher than the break-even requirement. In addition, with global prices of $70/tCO2 and $90/tCO2, break even is possible as long as the domestic price is within a certain range. Relatively, low domestic prices do not provide enough incentive for domestic agents to generate emission reductions above the break-even level. On the other hand, relatively high domestic prices raise the break-even quantity, Q^, to a level that the quantity of emission reductions realized at the domestic level is not enough to meet such a high level of break-even quantity. Figure 5 illustrates this situation with the global price of $70/tCO2. A domestic price below $20 does not provide enough incentives for domestic agents to generate emission reductions above the break-even level, with at least a 50% probability. To ensure break even with a 50% probability, the jurisdiction needs to set the domestic price in a range from $20 to $38 per ton.

      Median supply of emissions reductions relative to break-even requirement, for global price of $70/tCO2. Note: Figure assumes a minimum abatement requirement (tCO2) equal to 35 million tCO2 such that international payments are only made for abatement exceeding that level.

      Even within this price range, the jurisdiction still faces uncertainties of not breaking even, since the results only show the emissions reductions achieved or exceeded with a 50% probability. This uncertainty could entail a prohibitive level of risk for committing public funding or obtaining private sector investment (e.g., through a bond issuance) on the back of future carbon market revenues. This is because any emission reduction effort that produces a quantity below the break-even threshold translates to a negative wealth impact on the jurisdiction. Without the option to purchase insurance, therefore, the jurisdiction may decide not to undertake any emission reduction activities at all.

      We now simulate the provision of insurance, which could provide confidence to policymakers and potential investors by avoiding the risk of falling below break even. As an example, we consider the goal Qh, to be the 50% of emissions reduction at each domestic price level, and restrict attention to those levels of the domestic price that are sufficient to ensure break even with a 50% probability. We start with examining scenarios based on a global price of $70/tCO2 and a minimum abatement requirement for crediting 35 million tCO2. The expected levels of emission reductions when Q is at or above the 50% goal and when Q falls below this goal are shown in Supplementary Figure S2. The jurisdiction's emission reductions range from 18 to 30 million tCO2, with an average of 24 million tCO2 in the case when it is not able to meet its goal. When the jurisdiction can meet its goal, its expected emission reductions increase between 49 and 77 million tCO2, for prices from $20 to $38 per ton, that is, the jurisdiction's average emission is ~40 million tCO2 lower when the jurisdiction is not able to meet its goal.

      We now examine the wealth impact with and without the option to purchase performance insurance when a jurisdiction fails to meet its goal. In regards to the price of performance insurance, results from the simulation suggest, with Q¯ Q at 35 million tCO2, the actuarially fair full insurance ranges between $28 and $42/tCO2 for a global price between $70 and $90/tCO2. By construction, under an actuarially fair full insurance policy, the jurisdiction's expected wealth remains the same as without the insurance policy after deducting the price paid for the insurance premium. However, the key here is that without the insurance, the jurisdiction may otherwise decide not to undertake any emission reduction activities at all given the excessive level of risk. This is because any emission reduction effort that produces a quantity below the break-even threshold translates to a negative wealth impact on the jurisdiction.

      Figure 6 shows the negative impact on wealth, with and without the option to purchase performance insurance when the jurisdiction fails to meet its reduction goal Qh (set at the 50th percentile of the probability distribution). In the case when the global price of $70//tCO2 and  Q¯ at 35 million tCO2, without an option to purchase insurance, this translates to a potential loss of $199 million if the jurisdiction does not meet its goals and a potential loss of $338 million if the jurisdiction decided not to undertake any emission reduction activities. In the case when the global price of $90//tCO2 and Q¯ at 35 million tCO2, without an option to purchase insurance, this translates to a potential loss of $320 million if the jurisdiction does not meet its goals and a potential loss of $952 million if the jurisdiction decided not to undertake any emission reduction activities.

      Expected wealth with and without insurance, if jurisdiction fails to meet goal (Qh). Note: Vertical axis shows expected (probability-weighted) wealth of jurisdiction. Assumed minimum abatement requirement ( Q¯) equals 35 million tCO2 such that international payments are only made for abatement exceeding that level.

      As discussed earlier, in addition to making it possible for the jurisdiction to meet or go beyond the break-even emission reduction level, the provision of insurance could create an economic surplus when the jurisdiction's willingness to pay is lower than the actual payment to mitigate such risk. We now examine economic surplus. We also examine the effect on the economic surplus of setting the minimum abatement requirement for crediting Q¯ at 5, 15, and 25 million tCO2.

      Figure 7 shows the expected economic surplus for global prices of $70 and $90/tCO2 and the threshold requirement at 35 million tCO2. For an international price of $70, the economic average of the economic surplus is $81 million. For an international price of $90, the expected economic surplus jumps to $572 million, given that there is a jump not only in the price but also in the number of profitable outcomes. This is consistent with the expectation that as global price increases, with domestic price remaining constant, the quantity of emission reductions that could be covered by the international market increases. Figure 7 also illustrates the effect of changing the minimum abatement requirement for crediting. As discussed earlier, at the global price of $70/tCO2 and a minimum threshold requirement of 25 million tCO2, the jurisdiction will participate when the domestic price ranges from $20 to $38 per metric ton. When the minimum threshold requirement falls to 25, 15, and 5 million tCO2, the price range expands to $11 to $51, $5 to $60, and $2 to $67 per metric ton, respectively. The results also indicate that as the minimum crediting requirement decreases, at a given global price and with access to insurance, the positive impact on consumer surplus to emission reductions increases. This is because there is a wider range of domestic prices such that the jurisdiction can meet break even as the minimum abatement requirement decreases.

      Minimum abatement requirement and expected jurisdiction consumer surplus with insurance. Note: Vertical axis shows expected (probability-weighted) consumer surplus of jurisdiction. Assumed minimum abatement requirement (Q¯) varies as indicated across horizontal axis.

      Earlier, we noted that a jurisdiction that has established a record of meeting its threshold and break-even level could be eligible to access the insurance at a discounted price based on an assigned performance risk score. The better a jurisdiction's performance in meeting threshold and break-even quantity, the lower its performance score. As the score decreases, economic surplus increases. In our illustrative example, with a global price of $70 and $90 t/CO2 and a minimum requirement of 35 million metric tons, a one-point decrease in performance risk score increases the average economic surplus by about $3 million.

      Similar to reducing the minimum abatement requirement for crediting, a physical “buffer” of emissions reductions that could be tapped and sold to international buyers in the case of underperformance would provide another approach to insuring the risk of failing to meet a break-even level of reductions. This buffer could potentially be built up by jurisdiction over time, providing a form of self-insurance. Figure 8 shows the potential of such a buffer to unlock emissions reductions at the 50th percentile of supply for different levels of international prices, based on the different levels of domestic prices that the jurisdiction would be willing to offer that is consistent with break even, as shown in Figure 3. The buffer level is varied at 5 million ton intervals. No buffer is needed to allow reductions consistent with break even at prices of $70 and $90, but emissions reductions are not feasible at lower prices without a buffer. However, a buffer of 0–5, 5–10, 10–15, and 15–20 million tons, respectively, enables emissions reductions consistent with break even at international prices of $50, $40, $30, and $20/t CO2. Progressively greater buffers allow for greater reductions at each price level. Notably, for most of the price ranges and buffer sizes, each million ton of buffer enables more than 1 million ton of emissions reductions (a purely one-to-one linear relationship with the buffer is illustrated by the 45-degree line in black).

      Performance buffer and median supply of emissions reductions at or above break-even, by different global prices. Note: Assumed minimum abatement requirement (Q¯) equals 35 million tCO2 such that international payments are only made for abatement exceeding that level.

      The relationship between a buffer and the feasible emission reductions consistent with break even varies according to different percentiles of the supply distribution (Supplementary Figure S3). A buffer of 10–15 million tons is needed to ensure break even if it is necessary to have a 95% confidence level of supply. The required buffer size falls to 5–10 million tons at the 50th (median) and 75th percentiles, at 0–5 million tons at the 25th percentile, and no buffer at the 5th percentile of supply. This shows how greater reductions are feasible if the jurisdiction can take on more risk of not breaking even, or similarly if the jurisdiction can increase its confidence in the feasibility of different levels of supply.

      5. Discussion

      There is increasing consensus around the environmental and social benefits of moving from small to larger scale emissions reductions under carbon market crediting systems for REDD+ (COICA, 2023). However, the mobilization of large-scale finance will be necessary to implement these approaches. This study demonstrates the critical role of performance uncertainty in constraining the potential for large-scale mitigation supply when payments are contingent on emissions reductions exceeding a threshold level and when there is a need to break even on payments to domestic actors. This would be the case of a jurisdiction that is budget constrained, rather than able to finance emissions reductions with its own domestic resources to meet climate and/or other environmental and social goals. This would also be the case for private investors or other private actors investing with the requirement of a commercial return.

      One approach would entail lowering the performance requirements, but this would have tradeoffs with environmental integrity, also potentially limiting demand. Higher international prices could also compensate for the risk but could greatly limit the demand. Our numerical simulations likely overstate the level of prices that will be needed as it is based on cost curves estimated from the price sensitivity of historic land-use decisions rather than the range of government policies (e.g., law enforcement, designation of protected areas) that have demonstrated potential to reduce emissions at low budgetary costs. We also consider the case where the jurisdiction only seeks to cover its budgetary costs without considering the economic benefits to local actors. Different jurisdictions may also have higher levels of risk tolerance. Nevertheless, our analysis suggests that uncertainty over performance could require significantly higher prices to assure break even. Performance uncertainty is, thus, an important concern for REDD+ and other forms of large-scale emissions reductions. Even if uncertainties can be characterized, the risk of failing short on performance is likely to be a powerful hindrance to public and private investors that are seeking to finance high-quality and high-integrity emissions reductions at scale.

      We illustrate how insurance has the potential to play an important role in addressing this risk and mitigating the barriers to large-scale public and private investments. We show that actuarially fair insurance would allow jurisdictions to deliver large-scale emissions reductions despite performance uncertainty. Based on our illustrative simulations, given sufficiently high carbon prices, jurisdictions would be willing to pay for insurance and could develop a significant welfare surplus from the purchase of insurance to mitigate uncertainties over performance. As jurisdictions can develop a track record of performance, insurance costs could fall, providing further welfare gains.

      Major insurance companies have already identified promoting natural climate solutions, including forest protection, as a top priority for new insurance products as well as direct investments (e.g., AXA, 2022). However, it may be difficult for private companies to provide this insurance given unfamiliarity with the likely probabilities and potential concerns over the moral hazard, such that jurisdictions receiving insurance will have lower incentives to manage risks, particularly if insurance is not conditional on meeting a particular level of performance. A central feature of REDD+ is that it is performance-based. A concern could be that access to insurance might encourage jurisdictions to underperform. Given the high cost of insurance, this is less likely to occur if future insurance rates are conditioned on past performance, creating an incentive for jurisdictions to establish a successful track record.

      The challenges faced by private insurers suggest a potential role for philanthropy and potential public and multilateral donors and development finance institutions to work with jurisdictions and private insurers to jump-start the mechanism. Organizations such as the World Bank, Green Climate Fund (GCF), and Development Finance Corporation, together with philanthropic and public donors could potentially act as reinsurers to facilitate the creation of insurance businesses for REDD+ and reduce insurance costs with a consequential increase of private investment in jurisdictional REDD+. They might also offer insurance directly to jurisdictions on a concessional basis, based on a clear definition, monitoring, and verification of the investments to be made by the jurisdiction. Philanthropic and public donors also have an important role to play in supporting jurisdictions in capacity development and other investments that reduce risks of non-performance.

      While insurance could play an important role to unlock large-scale reductions, the creation of a performance buffer offers the nonlinear potential to unlock supply. Such buffer could be accumulated at the level of a jurisdiction over time (or across different actors within a jurisdiction) to enable self-insurance or could potentially be funded initially by philanthropic or public donors. A question will be the willingness of the buyers to pay for buffer tons to “top up” jurisdictional performance to ensure the break-even level of reductions is met. There is also potential for a pooled buffer across jurisdictions if buyers or other funders would be willing to accept reductions that are not tied to any particular location. Furthermore, the greater the flexibility of the buyers, the greater the potential to develop a buffer with a greater set of emissions reductions from different time periods and potentially different types of emission reduction activities.

      Insurance and a performance buffer could not only be used as stand-alone strategies but also have potential synergies for a mixed strategy to reduce risk and deliver high-quality emissions reductions. Insurance could help enable emissions reductions that support the creation of a buffer over time. Furthermore, the creation of a buffer at the level of a jurisdiction could in turn make a jurisdiction more insurable. Potential insurance providers themselves may also build up a buffer as the basis for their willingness to provide insurance or act as re-insurers.

      6. Conclusion

      There is a growing awareness of the importance of credit quality and the importance of large-scale crediting approaches for protecting forests. Buyers of REDD+ emissions reductions are looking for emissions reductions that would satisfy strict jurisdictional crediting criteria such as the ART-TREES standards used by the LEAF Coalition. Higher quality standards may make emission reductions more expensive, but protection and restoration of tropical forests remain the most cost-efficient mechanism to reduce emissions, with a benefit-cost ratio of >5 (Fuss et al., 2021). In addition, REDD+ can provide a large volume of emissions reduction in a timely manner when it is needed most to narrow the emissions. Nevertheless, scaling up REDD+ requires both private and public investments.

      We develop a conceptual model and numerical simulations that demonstrate the potential power of REDD+ performance insurance and buffer creation strategy as important instruments to scale up REDD+ supply under jurisdictional crediting programs. Our analysis demonstrates how uncertainty over future performance can significantly increase the cost and decrease potential investment when there is a performance threshold that must be achieved before crediting begins. We, then, show how insurance mechanisms are a solution that could reduce risks and unlock environmental and economic benefits.

      We considered the case where the jurisdictional government is the primary actor and can obtain a form of actuarially-fair revenue insurance to mitigate the risk. We also examine the case of a performance buffer to mitigate risk. In practice, a combination of instruments could be used. There may also be important uncertainties about the performance of government authorities, rather than about more decentralized local agents. Performance insurance and buffers could thus be applied at different levels of performance from national, subnational, and actor-specific levels. A surety bond is one widely used approach in construction and public works projects where contractors must post a bond that provides insurance to investors or other clients against the risk of default (Jing et al., 2020; Giacomelli and Passalacqua, 2021). In the case of jurisdictional REDD+ and other climate mitigation, such a mechanism could be appropriate at the level of different local agents, project developers, or government authorities depending on the nature of the performance risk and who is closest to managing it.

      The insurance and simulation model could be extended to consider multiple periods of crediting, including the potential resetting of the baseline over time. Additional research could also focus on empirical estimation of potential performance risks to support estimates of actuarially fair insurance rates. Research could also inform how risks can be mitigated through different program designs for jurisdictional REDD+ programs, as well as how these could be diversified at the international level. This could include spatial designs for reducing risks of reversals (McCallister et al., 2022), payments for landowners indexed to agricultural commodity prices (Engel et al., 2021), as well as financial approaches to address the underlying pressures on forests [e.g., via a revolving fund to support the intensification of cattle running on already deforested land instead of additional deforestation (Golub et al., 2021)].

      High-integrity carbon markets and other forms of result-based finance will be needed to protect tropical forests and achieve climate mitigation at the scales and speed required. However, given a broad set of uncertainties at this early stage of market implementation, result-based finance approaches that require ambitious performance entail the risk that could significantly diminish government and private investors' appetite to commit capital at sufficient scales to unlock the required mitigation. Once these programs are underway, this should simplify further rounds of insurance by providing more data as well as emissions reductions that could potentially start building a buffer that could support future rounds of insurance. Private insurers and philanthropic and public donors have a critical role to play in kickstarting and building an insurance market that can de-risk these programs and unlock natural climate solutions and other forms of urgent climate and nature protection at scale.

      Data availability statement

      The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/Supplementary material, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

      Author contributions

      KKC, AG, and RL jointly designed research, developed conceptual model, conducted simulations, and wrote the manuscript. All authors contributed to the article and approved the submitted version.

      The authors thank Peter C. Goldmark, Jr. for inspiration on the value of performance bonds to unlock large-scale investment in forest protection.

      Conflict of interest

      The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

      Publisher's note

      All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

      Supplementary material

      The Supplementary Material for this article can be found online at: /articles/10.3389/ffgc.2023.1062551/full#supplementary-material

      1While this downscaling approach serves for illustrative purposes, a specific analysis would be needed for a particular application to Mato Grosso or other jurisdiction given that opportunity costs and associated uncertainties are likely to vary widely across jurisdictions.

      References ART (2021). The REDD+Environmental Excellence Standard (TREES), Version 2.0. Arlington, VA: Winrock International. Available online at: https://www.artredd.org AXA (2022). Climate and Biodiversity Report: Accelerating Transition. Paris, France. Busch J. Engelmann J. Cook-Patton S. C. Griscom B. W. Kroeger T. Possingham H. . (2019). Potential for low-cost carbon dioxide removal through tropical reforestation. Nat. Climate Chang. 9, 463466. 10.1038/s41558-019-0485-x COICA CI, EDF, IPAM, TNC, WCS, WRI and WWF. (2023). Tropical Forest Carbon Credit Integrity Guide for Companies: Differentiating Tropical Forest Carbon Credits by Impact, Quality, and Scale. Washington, DC. Defries R. Ahuja R. Friedman J. Gordon D. Hamburg S. P. Kerr S. . (2022). Land management can contribute to net zero. Science. 376, 11631165. 10.1126/science.abo061335679411 Ecosystem Marketplace (2022). The Art of Integrity: Ecosystem Marketplace's State of the Voluntary Carbon Market 2022 Q3. Washington, DC: Forest Trends. Engel S. Palmer C. Taschini L. Urech S. (2021). Conservation payments under uncertainty. Land Econ. 91, 3656. 10.3368/le.91.1.36 EY (2022). Essential, Expensive and Evolving: The Outlook for Carbon Credits and Offsets. Sydney, Australia: EY Net Zero Centre Report. Frank R. H. (2021). Microeconomics and Behavior. New York: McGraw-Hill. Fuss S. Golub A. Lubowski R. (2021). The economic value of tropical forests in meeting global climate stabilization goals. Global Sustainabil. 4, 111. 10.1017/sus.2020.34 Giacomelli J. Passalacqua L. (2021). Unsustainability risk of bid bonds in public tenders. Mathematics. 9, 2385. 10.3390/math9192385 Golub A. Herrera D. Leslie G. Pietracci B. Lubowski R. (2021). A real options framework for reducing emissions from deforestation: Reconciling short-term incentives with long-term benefits from conservation and agricultural intensification. Ecosys. Serv. 49, 101275. 10.1016/j.ecoser.2021.101275 Griscom B. W. Adams J. Ellis P. W. Houghton R. A. Lomax G. Miteva D. A. . (2017). Natural Climate Solutions, in Proceedings of the National Academies of Science. 10.1073/pnas.171046511429078344 Hayashi T. (2021). Efficiency of allocation, in Microeconomic Theory for the Social Sciences. Singapore: Springer. 10.1007/978-981-16-3541-0_12 Jing J. Deng X. Maqbool R. Rashid Y. Ashfaq S. (2020). Default behaviors of contractors under surety bond in construction industry based on evolutionary game model. Sustainability. 12, 9162. 10.3390/su12219162 Kirkwood C. W. (2004). Approximating risk aversion in decision analysis applications. Deci. Anal. 1, 5167. 10.1287/deca.1030.0007 Lubowski R. (2021). Ramping up Efforts: The LEAF Coalition for tropical forest protection and climate collaboration. Carbon Mech. Rev. 9, 4450. Mas-Colell A. Whinston M. D. Green J. R. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. McCallister M. Krasovskiy A. Platov A. Pietracci B. Golub A. Lubowski R. . (2022). Forest protection and permanence of reduced emissions. Front. Forests Global Chang. 29:928518. 10.3389/ffgc.2022.92851824865818 McNamee P. Celona J. (1990). Decision Analysis with Supertree, Second Edition. South San Francisco, CA: Scientific Press. Schwartzman S. Lubowski R. Pacala S. W. Keohane N O. Kerr S. Oppenheimer M. (2021). Environmental integrity of emissions reductions depends on scale and systemic changes, not sector of origin. Environ. Res. Lett. 16, 091001. 10.1088/1748-9326/ac18e8 van Benthem A. Kerr S. (2013). Scale and Transfers in International Emissions Offset Programs. J. Public Econ. 107, 3146. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.08.004 Wunder S. Duchelle A. E. Sassi C. D. Sills E. O. Simonet G. Sunderlin W. D. (2020). REDD+ in theory and practice: how lessons from local projects can inform jurisdictional approaches. Front. Forests Global Chang. 3, 11. 10.3389/ffgc.2020.00011
      ‘Oh, my dear Thomas, you haven’t heard the terrible news then?’ she said. ‘I thought you would be sure to have seen it placarded somewhere. Alice went straight to her room, and I haven’t seen her since, though I repeatedly knocked at the door, which she has locked on the inside, and I’m sure it’s most unnatural of her not to let her own mother comfort her. It all happened in a moment: I have always said those great motor-cars shouldn’t be allowed to career about the streets, especially when they are all paved with cobbles as they are at Easton Haven, which are{331} so slippery when it’s wet. He slipped, and it went over him in a moment.’ My thanks were few and awkward, for there still hung to the missive a basting thread, and it was as warm as a nestling bird. I bent low--everybody was emotional in those days--kissed the fragrant thing, thrust it into my bosom, and blushed worse than Camille. "What, the Corner House victim? Is that really a fact?" "My dear child, I don't look upon it in that light at all. The child gave our picturesque friend a certain distinction--'My husband is dead, and this is my only child,' and all that sort of thing. It pays in society." leave them on the steps of a foundling asylum in order to insure [See larger version] Interoffice guff says you're planning definite moves on your own, J. O., and against some opposition. Is the Colonel so poor or so grasping—or what? Albert could not speak, for he felt as if his brains and teeth were rattling about inside his head. The rest of[Pg 188] the family hunched together by the door, the boys gaping idiotically, the girls in tears. "Now you're married." The host was called in, and unlocked a drawer in which they were deposited. The galleyman, with visible reluctance, arrayed himself in the garments, and he was observed to shudder more than once during the investiture of the dead man's apparel. HoME香京julia种子在线播放 ENTER NUMBET 0016gzwolfs.com.cn
      www.jjhgames.com.cn
      www.gidnht.com.cn
      www.jlszzxxx.com.cn
      www.szeconn.com.cn
      riywtf.com.cn
      www.v5d1h.net.cn
      www.newjia.com.cn
      www.ricpsd.com.cn
      pietqb.com.cn
      处女被大鸡巴操 强奸乱伦小说图片 俄罗斯美女爱爱图 调教强奸学生 亚洲女的穴 夜来香图片大全 美女性强奸电影 手机版色中阁 男性人体艺术素描图 16p成人 欧美性爱360 电影区 亚洲电影 欧美电影 经典三级 偷拍自拍 动漫电影 乱伦电影 变态另类 全部电 类似狠狠鲁的网站 黑吊操白逼图片 韩国黄片种子下载 操逼逼逼逼逼 人妻 小说 p 偷拍10幼女自慰 极品淫水很多 黄色做i爱 日本女人人体电影快播看 大福国小 我爱肏屄美女 mmcrwcom 欧美多人性交图片 肥臀乱伦老头舔阴帝 d09a4343000019c5 西欧人体艺术b xxoo激情短片 未成年人的 插泰国人夭图片 第770弾み1 24p 日本美女性 交动态 eee色播 yantasythunder 操无毛少女屄 亚洲图片你懂的女人 鸡巴插姨娘 特级黄 色大片播 左耳影音先锋 冢本友希全集 日本人体艺术绿色 我爱被舔逼 内射 幼 美阴图 喷水妹子高潮迭起 和后妈 操逼 美女吞鸡巴 鸭个自慰 中国女裸名单 操逼肥臀出水换妻 色站裸体义术 中国行上的漏毛美女叫什么 亚洲妹性交图 欧美美女人裸体人艺照 成人色妹妹直播 WWW_JXCT_COM r日本女人性淫乱 大胆人艺体艺图片 女同接吻av 碰碰哥免费自拍打炮 艳舞写真duppid1 88电影街拍视频 日本自拍做爱qvod 实拍美女性爱组图 少女高清av 浙江真实乱伦迅雷 台湾luanlunxiaoshuo 洛克王国宠物排行榜 皇瑟电影yy频道大全 红孩儿连连看 阴毛摄影 大胆美女写真人体艺术摄影 和风骚三个媳妇在家做爱 性爱办公室高清 18p2p木耳 大波撸影音 大鸡巴插嫩穴小说 一剧不超两个黑人 阿姨诱惑我快播 幼香阁千叶县小学生 少女妇女被狗强奸 曰人体妹妹 十二岁性感幼女 超级乱伦qvod 97爱蜜桃ccc336 日本淫妇阴液 av海量资源999 凤凰影视成仁 辰溪四中艳照门照片 先锋模特裸体展示影片 成人片免费看 自拍百度云 肥白老妇女 女爱人体图片 妈妈一女穴 星野美夏 日本少女dachidu 妹子私处人体图片 yinmindahuitang 舔无毛逼影片快播 田莹疑的裸体照片 三级电影影音先锋02222 妻子被外国老头操 观月雏乃泥鳅 韩国成人偷拍自拍图片 强奸5一9岁幼女小说 汤姆影院av图片 妹妹人艺体图 美女大驱 和女友做爱图片自拍p 绫川まどか在线先锋 那么嫩的逼很少见了 小女孩做爱 处女好逼连连看图图 性感美女在家做爱 近距离抽插骚逼逼 黑屌肏金毛屄 日韩av美少女 看喝尿尿小姐日逼色色色网图片 欧美肛交新视频 美女吃逼逼 av30线上免费 伊人在线三级经典 新视觉影院t6090影院 最新淫色电影网址 天龙影院远古手机版 搞老太影院 插进美女的大屁股里 私人影院加盟费用 www258dd 求一部电影里面有一个二猛哥 深肛交 日本萌妹子人体艺术写真图片 插入屄眼 美女的木奶 中文字幕黄色网址影视先锋 九号女神裸 和骚人妻偷情 和潘晓婷做爱 国模大尺度蜜桃 欧美大逼50p 西西人体成人 李宗瑞继母做爱原图物处理 nianhuawang 男鸡巴的视屏 � 97免费色伦电影 好色网成人 大姨子先锋 淫荡巨乳美女教师妈妈 性nuexiaoshuo WWW36YYYCOM 长春继续给力进屋就操小女儿套干破内射对白淫荡 农夫激情社区 日韩无码bt 欧美美女手掰嫩穴图片 日本援交偷拍自拍 入侵者日本在线播放 亚洲白虎偷拍自拍 常州高见泽日屄 寂寞少妇自卫视频 人体露逼图片 多毛外国老太 变态乱轮手机在线 淫荡妈妈和儿子操逼 伦理片大奶少女 看片神器最新登入地址sqvheqi345com账号群 麻美学姐无头 圣诞老人射小妞和强奸小妞动话片 亚洲AV女老师 先锋影音欧美成人资源 33344iucoom zV天堂电影网 宾馆美女打炮视频 色五月丁香五月magnet 嫂子淫乱小说 张歆艺的老公 吃奶男人视频在线播放 欧美色图男女乱伦 avtt2014ccvom 性插色欲香影院 青青草撸死你青青草 99热久久第一时间 激情套图卡通动漫 幼女裸聊做爱口交 日本女人被强奸乱伦 草榴社区快播 2kkk正在播放兽骑 啊不要人家小穴都湿了 www猎奇影视 A片www245vvcomwwwchnrwhmhzcn 搜索宜春院av wwwsee78co 逼奶鸡巴插 好吊日AV在线视频19gancom 熟女伦乱图片小说 日本免费av无码片在线开苞 鲁大妈撸到爆 裸聊官网 德国熟女xxx 新不夜城论坛首页手机 女虐男网址 男女做爱视频华为网盘 激情午夜天亚洲色图 内裤哥mangent 吉沢明歩制服丝袜WWWHHH710COM 屌逼在线试看 人体艺体阿娇艳照 推荐一个可以免费看片的网站如果被QQ拦截请复制链接在其它浏览器打开xxxyyy5comintr2a2cb551573a2b2e 欧美360精品粉红鲍鱼 教师调教第一页 聚美屋精品图 中韩淫乱群交 俄罗斯撸撸片 把鸡巴插进小姨子的阴道 干干AV成人网 aolasoohpnbcn www84ytom 高清大量潮喷www27dyycom 宝贝开心成人 freefronvideos人母 嫩穴成人网gggg29com 逼着舅妈给我口交肛交彩漫画 欧美色色aV88wwwgangguanscom 老太太操逼自拍视频 777亚洲手机在线播放 有没有夫妻3p小说 色列漫画淫女 午间色站导航 欧美成人处女色大图 童颜巨乳亚洲综合 桃色性欲草 色眯眯射逼 无码中文字幕塞外青楼这是一个 狂日美女老师人妻 爱碰网官网 亚洲图片雅蠛蝶 快播35怎么搜片 2000XXXX电影 新谷露性家庭影院 深深候dvd播放 幼齿用英语怎么说 不雅伦理无需播放器 国外淫荡图片 国外网站幼幼嫩网址 成年人就去色色视频快播 我鲁日日鲁老老老我爱 caoshaonvbi 人体艺术avav 性感性色导航 韩国黄色哥来嫖网站 成人网站美逼 淫荡熟妇自拍 欧美色惰图片 北京空姐透明照 狼堡免费av视频 www776eom 亚洲无码av欧美天堂网男人天堂 欧美激情爆操 a片kk266co 色尼姑成人极速在线视频 国语家庭系列 蒋雯雯 越南伦理 色CC伦理影院手机版 99jbbcom 大鸡巴舅妈 国产偷拍自拍淫荡对话视频 少妇春梦射精 开心激动网 自拍偷牌成人 色桃隐 撸狗网性交视频 淫荡的三位老师 伦理电影wwwqiuxia6commqiuxia6com 怡春院分站 丝袜超短裙露脸迅雷下载 色制服电影院 97超碰好吊色男人 yy6080理论在线宅男日韩福利大全 大嫂丝袜 500人群交手机在线 5sav 偷拍熟女吧 口述我和妹妹的欲望 50p电脑版 wwwavtttcon 3p3com 伦理无码片在线看 欧美成人电影图片岛国性爱伦理电影 先锋影音AV成人欧美 我爱好色 淫电影网 WWW19MMCOM 玛丽罗斯3d同人动画h在线看 动漫女孩裸体 超级丝袜美腿乱伦 1919gogo欣赏 大色逼淫色 www就是撸 激情文学网好骚 A级黄片免费 xedd5com 国内的b是黑的 快播美国成年人片黄 av高跟丝袜视频 上原保奈美巨乳女教师在线观看 校园春色都市激情fefegancom 偷窥自拍XXOO 搜索看马操美女 人本女优视频 日日吧淫淫 人妻巨乳影院 美国女子性爱学校 大肥屁股重口味 啪啪啪啊啊啊不要 操碰 japanfreevideoshome国产 亚州淫荡老熟女人体 伦奸毛片免费在线看 天天影视se 樱桃做爱视频 亚卅av在线视频 x奸小说下载 亚洲色图图片在线 217av天堂网 东方在线撸撸-百度 幼幼丝袜集 灰姑娘的姐姐 青青草在线视频观看对华 86papa路con 亚洲1AV 综合图片2区亚洲 美国美女大逼电影 010插插av成人网站 www色comwww821kxwcom 播乐子成人网免费视频在线观看 大炮撸在线影院 ,www4KkKcom 野花鲁最近30部 wwwCC213wapwww2233ww2download 三客优最新地址 母亲让儿子爽的无码视频 全国黄色片子 欧美色图美国十次 超碰在线直播 性感妖娆操 亚洲肉感熟女色图 a片A毛片管看视频 8vaa褋芯屑 333kk 川岛和津实视频 在线母子乱伦对白 妹妹肥逼五月 亚洲美女自拍 老婆在我面前小说 韩国空姐堪比情趣内衣 干小姐综合 淫妻色五月 添骚穴 WM62COM 23456影视播放器 成人午夜剧场 尼姑福利网 AV区亚洲AV欧美AV512qucomwwwc5508com 经典欧美骚妇 震动棒露出 日韩丝袜美臀巨乳在线 av无限吧看 就去干少妇 色艺无间正面是哪集 校园春色我和老师做爱 漫画夜色 天海丽白色吊带 黄色淫荡性虐小说 午夜高清播放器 文20岁女性荫道口图片 热国产热无码热有码 2015小明发布看看算你色 百度云播影视 美女肏屄屄乱轮小说 家族舔阴AV影片 邪恶在线av有码 父女之交 关于处女破处的三级片 极品护士91在线 欧美虐待女人视频的网站 享受老太太的丝袜 aaazhibuo 8dfvodcom成人 真实自拍足交 群交男女猛插逼 妓女爱爱动态 lin35com是什么网站 abp159 亚洲色图偷拍自拍乱伦熟女抠逼自慰 朝国三级篇 淫三国幻想 免费的av小电影网站 日本阿v视频免费按摩师 av750c0m 黄色片操一下 巨乳少女车震在线观看 操逼 免费 囗述情感一乱伦岳母和女婿 WWW_FAMITSU_COM 偷拍中国少妇在公车被操视频 花也真衣论理电影 大鸡鸡插p洞 新片欧美十八岁美少 进击的巨人神thunderftp 西方美女15p 深圳哪里易找到老女人玩视频 在线成人有声小说 365rrr 女尿图片 我和淫荡的小姨做爱 � 做爱技术体照 淫妇性爱 大学生私拍b 第四射狠狠射小说 色中色成人av社区 和小姨子乱伦肛交 wwwppp62com 俄罗斯巨乳人体艺术 骚逼阿娇 汤芳人体图片大胆 大胆人体艺术bb私处 性感大胸骚货 哪个网站幼女的片多 日本美女本子把 色 五月天 婷婷 快播 美女 美穴艺术 色百合电影导航 大鸡巴用力 孙悟空操美少女战士 狠狠撸美女手掰穴图片 古代女子与兽类交 沙耶香套图 激情成人网区 暴风影音av播放 动漫女孩怎么插第3个 mmmpp44 黑木麻衣无码ed2k 淫荡学姐少妇 乱伦操少女屄 高中性爱故事 骚妹妹爱爱图网 韩国模特剪长发 大鸡巴把我逼日了 中国张柏芝做爱片中国张柏芝做爱片中国张柏芝做爱片中国张柏芝做爱片中国张柏芝做爱片 大胆女人下体艺术图片 789sss 影音先锋在线国内情侣野外性事自拍普通话对白 群撸图库 闪现君打阿乐 ady 小说 插入表妹嫩穴小说 推荐成人资源 网络播放器 成人台 149大胆人体艺术 大屌图片 骚美女成人av 春暖花开春色性吧 女亭婷五月 我上了同桌的姐姐 恋夜秀场主播自慰视频 yzppp 屄茎 操屄女图 美女鲍鱼大特写 淫乱的日本人妻山口玲子 偷拍射精图 性感美女人体艺木图片 种马小说完本 免费电影院 骑士福利导航导航网站 骚老婆足交 国产性爱一级电影 欧美免费成人花花性都 欧美大肥妞性爱视频 家庭乱伦网站快播 偷拍自拍国产毛片 金发美女也用大吊来开包 缔D杏那 yentiyishu人体艺术ytys WWWUUKKMCOM 女人露奶 � 苍井空露逼 老荡妇高跟丝袜足交 偷偷和女友的朋友做爱迅雷 做爱七十二尺 朱丹人体合成 麻腾由纪妃 帅哥撸播种子图 鸡巴插逼动态图片 羙国十次啦中文 WWW137AVCOM 神斗片欧美版华语 有气质女人人休艺术 由美老师放屁电影 欧美女人肉肏图片 白虎种子快播 国产自拍90后女孩 美女在床上疯狂嫩b 饭岛爱最后之作 幼幼强奸摸奶 色97成人动漫 两性性爱打鸡巴插逼 新视觉影院4080青苹果影院 嗯好爽插死我了 阴口艺术照 李宗瑞电影qvod38 爆操舅母 亚洲色图七七影院 被大鸡巴操菊花 怡红院肿么了 成人极品影院删除 欧美性爱大图色图强奸乱 欧美女子与狗随便性交 苍井空的bt种子无码 熟女乱伦长篇小说 大色虫 兽交幼女影音先锋播放 44aad be0ca93900121f9b 先锋天耗ばさ无码 欧毛毛女三级黄色片图 干女人黑木耳照 日本美女少妇嫩逼人体艺术 sesechangchang 色屄屄网 久久撸app下载 色图色噜 美女鸡巴大奶 好吊日在线视频在线观看 透明丝袜脚偷拍自拍 中山怡红院菜单 wcwwwcom下载 骑嫂子 亚洲大色妣 成人故事365ahnet 丝袜家庭教mp4 幼交肛交 妹妹撸撸大妈 日本毛爽 caoprom超碰在email 关于中国古代偷窥的黄片 第一会所老熟女下载 wwwhuangsecome 狼人干综合新地址HD播放 变态儿子强奸乱伦图 强奸电影名字 2wwwer37com 日本毛片基地一亚洲AVmzddcxcn 暗黑圣经仙桃影院 37tpcocn 持月真由xfplay 好吊日在线视频三级网 我爱背入李丽珍 电影师傅床戏在线观看 96插妹妹sexsex88com 豪放家庭在线播放 桃花宝典极夜著豆瓜网 安卓系统播放神器 美美网丝袜诱惑 人人干全免费视频xulawyercn av无插件一本道 全国色五月 操逼电影小说网 good在线wwwyuyuelvcom www18avmmd 撸波波影视无插件 伊人幼女成人电影 会看射的图片 小明插看看 全裸美女扒开粉嫩b 国人自拍性交网站 萝莉白丝足交本子 七草ちとせ巨乳视频 摇摇晃晃的成人电影 兰桂坊成社人区小说www68kqcom 舔阴论坛 久撸客一撸客色国内外成人激情在线 明星门 欧美大胆嫩肉穴爽大片 www牛逼插 性吧星云 少妇性奴的屁眼 人体艺术大胆mscbaidu1imgcn 最新久久色色成人版 l女同在线 小泽玛利亚高潮图片搜索 女性裸b图 肛交bt种子 最热门有声小说 人间添春色 春色猜谜字 樱井莉亚钢管舞视频 小泽玛利亚直美6p 能用的h网 还能看的h网 bl动漫h网 开心五月激 东京热401 男色女色第四色酒色网 怎么下载黄色小说 黄色小说小栽 和谐图城 乐乐影院 色哥导航 特色导航 依依社区 爱窝窝在线 色狼谷成人 91porn 包要你射电影 色色3A丝袜 丝袜妹妹淫网 爱色导航(荐) 好男人激情影院 坏哥哥 第七色 色久久 人格分裂 急先锋 撸撸射中文网 第一会所综合社区 91影院老师机 东方成人激情 怼莪影院吹潮 老鸭窝伊人无码不卡无码一本道 av女柳晶电影 91天生爱风流作品 深爱激情小说私房婷婷网 擼奶av 567pao 里番3d一家人野外 上原在线电影 水岛津实透明丝袜 1314酒色 网旧网俺也去 0855影院 在线无码私人影院 搜索 国产自拍 神马dy888午夜伦理达达兔 农民工黄晓婷 日韩裸体黑丝御姐 屈臣氏的燕窝面膜怎么样つぼみ晶エリーの早漏チ○ポ强化合宿 老熟女人性视频 影音先锋 三上悠亚ol 妹妹影院福利片 hhhhhhhhsxo 午夜天堂热的国产 强奸剧场 全裸香蕉视频无码 亚欧伦理视频 秋霞为什么给封了 日本在线视频空天使 日韩成人aⅴ在线 日本日屌日屄导航视频 在线福利视频 日本推油无码av magnet 在线免费视频 樱井梨吮东 日本一本道在线无码DVD 日本性感诱惑美女做爱阴道流水视频 日本一级av 汤姆avtom在线视频 台湾佬中文娱乐线20 阿v播播下载 橙色影院 奴隶少女护士cg视频 汤姆在线影院无码 偷拍宾馆 业面紧急生级访问 色和尚有线 厕所偷拍一族 av女l 公交色狼优酷视频 裸体视频AV 人与兽肉肉网 董美香ol 花井美纱链接 magnet 西瓜影音 亚洲 自拍 日韩女优欧美激情偷拍自拍 亚洲成年人免费视频 荷兰免费成人电影 深喉呕吐XXⅩX 操石榴在线视频 天天色成人免费视频 314hu四虎 涩久免费视频在线观看 成人电影迅雷下载 能看见整个奶子的香蕉影院 水菜丽百度影音 gwaz079百度云 噜死你们资源站 主播走光视频合集迅雷下载 thumbzilla jappen 精品Av 古川伊织star598在线 假面女皇vip在线视频播放 国产自拍迷情校园 啪啪啪公寓漫画 日本阿AV 黄色手机电影 欧美在线Av影院 华裔电击女神91在线 亚洲欧美专区 1日本1000部免费视频 开放90后 波多野结衣 东方 影院av 页面升级紧急访问每天正常更新 4438Xchengeren 老炮色 a k福利电影 色欲影视色天天视频 高老庄aV 259LUXU-683 magnet 手机在线电影 国产区 欧美激情人人操网 国产 偷拍 直播 日韩 国内外激情在线视频网给 站长统计一本道人妻 光棍影院被封 紫竹铃取汁 ftp 狂插空姐嫩 xfplay 丈夫面前 穿靴子伪街 XXOO视频在线免费 大香蕉道久在线播放 电棒漏电嗨过头 充气娃能看下毛和洞吗 夫妻牲交 福利云点墦 yukun瑟妃 疯狂交换女友 国产自拍26页 腐女资源 百度云 日本DVD高清无码视频 偷拍,自拍AV伦理电影 A片小视频福利站。 大奶肥婆自拍偷拍图片 交配伊甸园 超碰在线视频自拍偷拍国产 小热巴91大神 rctd 045 类似于A片 超美大奶大学生美女直播被男友操 男友问 你的衣服怎么脱掉的 亚洲女与黑人群交视频一 在线黄涩 木内美保步兵番号 鸡巴插入欧美美女的b舒服 激情在线国产自拍日韩欧美 国语福利小视频在线观看 作爱小视颍 潮喷合集丝袜无码mp4 做爱的无码高清视频 牛牛精品 伊aⅤ在线观看 savk12 哥哥搞在线播放 在线电一本道影 一级谍片 250pp亚洲情艺中心,88 欧美一本道九色在线一 wwwseavbacom色av吧 cos美女在线 欧美17,18ⅹⅹⅹ视频 自拍嫩逼 小电影在线观看网站 筱田优 贼 水电工 5358x视频 日本69式视频有码 b雪福利导航 韩国女主播19tvclub在线 操逼清晰视频 丝袜美女国产视频网址导航 水菜丽颜射房间 台湾妹中文娱乐网 风吟岛视频 口交 伦理 日本熟妇色五十路免费视频 A级片互舔 川村真矢Av在线观看 亚洲日韩av 色和尚国产自拍 sea8 mp4 aV天堂2018手机在线 免费版国产偷拍a在线播放 狠狠 婷婷 丁香 小视频福利在线观看平台 思妍白衣小仙女被邻居强上 萝莉自拍有水 4484新视觉 永久发布页 977成人影视在线观看 小清新影院在线观 小鸟酱后丝后入百度云 旋风魅影四级 香蕉影院小黄片免费看 性爱直播磁力链接 小骚逼第一色影院 性交流的视频 小雪小视频bd 小视频TV禁看视频 迷奸AV在线看 nba直播 任你在干线 汤姆影院在线视频国产 624u在线播放 成人 一级a做爰片就在线看狐狸视频 小香蕉AV视频 www182、com 腿模简小育 学生做爱视频 秘密搜查官 快播 成人福利网午夜 一级黄色夫妻录像片 直接看的gav久久播放器 国产自拍400首页 sm老爹影院 谁知道隔壁老王网址在线 综合网 123西瓜影音 米奇丁香 人人澡人人漠大学生 色久悠 夜色视频你今天寂寞了吗? 菲菲影视城美国 被抄的影院 变态另类 欧美 成人 国产偷拍自拍在线小说 不用下载安装就能看的吃男人鸡巴视频 插屄视频 大贯杏里播放 wwwhhh50 233若菜奈央 伦理片天海翼秘密搜查官 大香蕉在线万色屋视频 那种漫画小说你懂的 祥仔电影合集一区 那里可以看澳门皇冠酒店a片 色自啪 亚洲aV电影天堂 谷露影院ar toupaizaixian sexbj。com 毕业生 zaixian mianfei 朝桐光视频 成人短视频在线直接观看 陈美霖 沈阳音乐学院 导航女 www26yjjcom 1大尺度视频 开平虐女视频 菅野雪松协和影视在线视频 华人play在线视频bbb 鸡吧操屄视频 多啪啪免费视频 悠草影院 金兰策划网 (969) 橘佑金短视频 国内一极刺激自拍片 日本制服番号大全magnet 成人动漫母系 电脑怎么清理内存 黄色福利1000 dy88午夜 偷拍中学生洗澡磁力链接 花椒相机福利美女视频 站长推荐磁力下载 mp4 三洞轮流插视频 玉兔miki热舞视频 夜生活小视频 爆乳人妖小视频 国内网红主播自拍福利迅雷下载 不用app的裸裸体美女操逼视频 变态SM影片在线观看 草溜影院元气吧 - 百度 - 百度 波推全套视频 国产双飞集合ftp 日本在线AV网 笔国毛片 神马影院女主播是我的邻居 影音资源 激情乱伦电影 799pao 亚洲第一色第一影院 av视频大香蕉 老梁故事汇希斯莱杰 水中人体磁力链接 下载 大香蕉黄片免费看 济南谭崔 避开屏蔽的岛a片 草破福利 要看大鸡巴操小骚逼的人的视频 黑丝少妇影音先锋 欧美巨乳熟女磁力链接 美国黄网站色大全 伦蕉在线久播 极品女厕沟 激情五月bd韩国电影 混血美女自摸和男友激情啪啪自拍诱人呻吟福利视频 人人摸人人妻做人人看 44kknn 娸娸原网 伊人欧美 恋夜影院视频列表安卓青青 57k影院 如果电话亭 avi 插爆骚女精品自拍 青青草在线免费视频1769TV 令人惹火的邻家美眉 影音先锋 真人妹子被捅动态图 男人女人做完爱视频15 表姐合租两人共处一室晚上她竟爬上了我的床 性爱教学视频 北条麻妃bd在线播放版 国产老师和师生 magnet wwwcctv1024 女神自慰 ftp 女同性恋做激情视频 欧美大胆露阴视频 欧美无码影视 好女色在线观看 后入肥臀18p 百度影视屏福利 厕所超碰视频 强奸mp magnet 欧美妹aⅴ免费线上看 2016年妞干网视频 5手机在线福利 超在线最视频 800av:cOm magnet 欧美性爱免播放器在线播放 91大款肥汤的性感美乳90后邻家美眉趴着窗台后入啪啪 秋霞日本毛片网站 cheng ren 在线视频 上原亚衣肛门无码解禁影音先锋 美脚家庭教师在线播放 尤酷伦理片 熟女性生活视频在线观看 欧美av在线播放喷潮 194avav 凤凰AV成人 - 百度 kbb9999 AV片AV在线AV无码 爱爱视频高清免费观看 黄色男女操b视频 观看 18AV清纯视频在线播放平台 成人性爱视频久久操 女性真人生殖系统双性人视频 下身插入b射精视频 明星潜规测视频 mp4 免賛a片直播绪 国内 自己 偷拍 在线 国内真实偷拍 手机在线 国产主播户外勾在线 三桥杏奈高清无码迅雷下载 2五福电影院凸凹频频 男主拿鱼打女主,高宝宝 色哥午夜影院 川村まや痴汉 草溜影院费全过程免费 淫小弟影院在线视频 laohantuiche 啪啪啪喷潮XXOO视频 青娱乐成人国产 蓝沢润 一本道 亚洲青涩中文欧美 神马影院线理论 米娅卡莉法的av 在线福利65535 欧美粉色在线 欧美性受群交视频1在线播放 极品喷奶熟妇在线播放 变态另类无码福利影院92 天津小姐被偷拍 磁力下载 台湾三级电髟全部 丝袜美腿偷拍自拍 偷拍女生性行为图 妻子的乱伦 白虎少妇 肏婶骚屄 外国大妈会阴照片 美少女操屄图片 妹妹自慰11p 操老熟女的b 361美女人体 360电影院樱桃 爱色妹妹亚洲色图 性交卖淫姿势高清图片一级 欧美一黑对二白 大色网无毛一线天 射小妹网站 寂寞穴 西西人体模特苍井空 操的大白逼吧 骚穴让我操 拉好友干女朋友3p